Share to:

A. D. Roy

A. D. Roy
Born
Andrew Donald Roy

28 June 1920
Died12 March 2003(2003-03-12) (aged 82)
London, England
NationalityBritish
Academic career
FieldEconomics
Alma materUniversity of Cambridge, (MA)
ContributionsRoy model on self-selection and income distributions
Roy's safety-first criterion

Andrew Donald Roy (28 June 1920 – 12 March 2003) was a British economist who is known for the Roy model of self-selection and income distribution and Roy's safety-first criterion.

Early life and education

Andrew Donald Roy was born 28 June 1920. His father, Donald Whatley Roy, was a physician. A. D. Roy began studies in mathematics at Sidney Sussex College, Cambridge, in 1938. He won the distinguished Tripos award in 1939 in mathematics. His studies were interrupted by the outbreak of World War II, and he eventually served in the Fourteenth Army in India. He fought in the Battle of Imphal which stemmed the Japanese invasion of India in 1944. During his service, Roy contracted jaundice and suffered a nervous collapse, which lingered in the form of depression. After the war, he returned to Cambridge to study economics and history and was awarded a second Tripos award in economics in 1948. He later married Katherine Juliet Grove-White, and the pair had a son, Donald James Roy, and two daughters. He completed his Master of Arts in Economics at Cambridge in 1950, reading under Professor Edward Austin Gossage Robinson. Roy died on 12 March 2003 of heart disease. (See Sullivan, 2011[1] for a more complete biography and Heckman and Sattinger, 2015[2] for an intellectual biography.)

Career

Roy was appointed Faculty Assistant Lecturer in Statistics at Cambridge University in 1949. In 1950, Roy was appointed Director of Economic Studies at Cambridge and then University Lecturer in Economics and Politics at Sidney Sussex College in 1951. While at Cambridge, Roy wrote an influential paper on productivity and the shape of the distribution of earnings[3] which he substantially generalized in his seminal 1951 article on self-selection and income inequality (Roy, 1951).[4] In addition, Roy made a fundamental contribution to portfolio theory in his paper ‘Safety First and the Holding of Assets’ (1952).[5]

Roy left Sidney Sussex in 1962 to serve as Economic Consultant and later Senior Economic Advisor to the Treasury. In 1964, Roy entered civil service, and worked for the Treasury, Department of Trade and Industry, Ministry of Defence, and Department of Health and Social Security. During this time, Roy addressed issues more closely related to macroeconomics such as labor productivity (Roy, 1982;[6] Roy and Wenban-Smith, 1983[7]).

Contributions

Roy (1951)[4] recognized that a major mechanism guiding assignment in the labor market is David Ricardo's principle of comparative advantage.[2] A worker choosing an occupation will compare the income from one occupation with the income from another occupation. To use the example provided by Roy in his 1951 paper, a person who chose trout fishing would have a comparative advantage at that activity compared to a person who chose rabbit catching. A second consequence of the choice of occupations is that the distribution of earnings is built up from the distributions of earnings in individual occupations. The distribution of earnings within an occupation is affected by the selection of workers into that occupation, as determined by ‘the association existing between any individual’s performance in the two occupations’ (Roy, 1951, p. 494).[4] Roy considers both positive and negative correlation between performances. As a result of the selection, the aggregate distribution of earnings depends on the occupations available to workers and their performances in different occupations.

Selection among alternative occupations, as described by Roy, draws on notions of potential outcomes used in the literature on the design of experiments (Neyman, 1923;[8] Cox, 1958[9]). Like later work by Quandt (1972),[10] Gronau (1974)[11] and Heckman (1974,[12] 1976[13]), he added a choice mechanism to the model of potential outcomes in the statistical literature determining allocations of individuals across sectors associated with outcomes.[14][15] Roy introduced economic decision-making into the determination of occupations and earnings and thereby anticipated procedures later used for the rigorous analysis of earnings data.

Roy's selection phenomenon has been applied and extended to a wide range of other contexts, including: choice of market versus non-market work and wage comparisons (Gronau, 1974;[11] Heckman, 1974,[12] 1976;[13] Lewis, 1974[16]); and more general decision rules (see the survey in Heckman and Vytlacil, 2007a[17]). His work also affected analysis of choice in: union versus non-union sectors (Lee, 1978[18]); levels of education (Willis and Rosen, 1979[19]); geographical region (Robinson and Tomes, 1982[20]); marital status (McElroy and Horney, 1981[21]); occupational choice (Miller, 1984[22]); piece rate versus salary pay structures (Lazear, 1986[23]); industry changers (Solon, 1988;[24] Gibbons and Katz, 1992[25]); immigration (Borjas, 1990[26]); and segmented labor markets (Magnac, 1991[27]). Flinn and Heckman (1982)[28] extend Roy's selection model by incorporating choices based on search. See French and Taber (2011)[29] for a comprehensive discussion of the use of the Roy model in labor economics.

Analysis of selection bias has led to substantial improvements in the evaluation of social programs (Heckman et al., 1996,[30] 1997;[31] Abbring and Heckman, 2007;[32] Heckman and Vytlacil, 2007a,[17] b[33]). A further extension considers general equilibrium models of income distribution and treatment effects (Heckman et al., 1998;[34] Abbring and Heckman, 2007[32]). The Roy (1951) model which analyzes potential outcomes using a choice mechanism improves on later, less clearly formulated work exposited in statistics under the rubric of the "Rubin model". See Heckman (2008)[15] and Heckman and Sattinger (2015).[2]

Roy also made a fundamental contribution to finance. His (1952)[5] paper is widely regarded as a contribution to portfolio theory co-equal with that of the Nobel-Prize winning analysis of Harry Markowitz (1952).[35] Both developed the mean-variance trade-off for a portfolio of correlated assets (Markowitz, 1991).[36] Reflecting on his 1952 work[35] and Roy's (1952)[5] paper, Markowitz wrote: ‘On the basis of Markowitz (1952), I am often called the father of modern portfolio theory (MPT), but Roy can claim an equal share of this honor’. (Markowitz, 1999, p. 6)[37] For a more extensive discussion of Roy's contribution to portfolio theory, see Bernstein (1992)[38] and Sullivan (2011).[1]

Publications

References

  1. ^ a b Sullivan, Edward J. (2011). Biddle, Jeff E.; Emmett, Ross B. (eds.). A.D. Roy: The Forgotten Father of Portfolio Theory Part 1. Vol. 29. Emerald Group Publishing Limited. pp. 73–82. doi:10.1108/S0743-4154(2011)000029A008. ISBN 9781780520070. {{cite book}}: |journal= ignored (help)
  2. ^ a b c Heckman, J. J.; Sattinger, M. (2015). "Introduction to 'The Distribution of Earnings and of Individual Output,' by A.D. Roy". Economic Journal. 125 (583): 378–402. doi:10.1111/ecoj.12226. PMC 4399962. PMID 25892742.
  3. ^ Roy, A. D. (1950). "The Distribution of Earnings and of Individual Output". Economic Journal. 60 (239): 489–505. doi:10.2307/2226792. JSTOR 2226792.
  4. ^ a b c Roy, A. D. (1951). "Some Thoughts on the Distribution of Earnings". Oxford Economic Papers. 3 (2): 135–146. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041827.
  5. ^ a b c Roy, A. D. (1952). "Safety First and the Holding of Assets". Econometrica. 20 (3): 431–449. doi:10.2307/1907413. JSTOR 1907413.
  6. ^ Roy, A. D. (1982). "Labour Productivity in 1980: An International Comparison". National Institute Economic Review. 101 (1): 26–37. doi:10.1177/002795018210100104. S2CID 154862307.
  7. ^ Roy, A. D.; Wenban-Smith, G. (1983). Trends in UK Productivity: A Production Function Approach. London, UK: National Institute of Economic and Social Research.
  8. ^ Neyman, J. (1923). "On the Application of Probability Theory to Agricultural Experiments". Roczniki Nauk Rolniczych. 10: 1–51.
  9. ^ Cox, D. R. (1958). Planning of Experiments. New York, NY: Wiley.
  10. ^ Quandt, R. (1972). "A New Approach to Estimating Switching Regressions". Journal of the American Statistical Association. 67 (338): 306–310. doi:10.2307/2284373. JSTOR 2284373.
  11. ^ a b Gronau, R. (1974). "Wage Comparisons–A Selectivity Bias". Journal of Political Economy. 82 (6): 1119–1143. doi:10.1086/260267. S2CID 153856057.
  12. ^ a b Heckman, J. J. (1974). "Shadow Prices, Market Wages, and Labor Supply". Econometrica. 42 (4): 679–694. doi:10.2307/1913937. JSTOR 1913937.
  13. ^ a b Heckman, J. J. (1976). "The Common Structure of Statistical Models of Truncation, Sample Selection and Limited Dependent Variables". Annals of Economic and Social Measurement. 5 (4): 475–492.
  14. ^ Heckman, 2008 discusses the contribution of economists to the Neyman–Fisher–Rubin literature on potential outcomes.
  15. ^ a b Heckman, J. J. (2008). "Econometric Causality". International Statistical Review. 76 (1): 1–27. doi:10.1111/j.1751-5823.2007.00024.x. S2CID 14318481.
  16. ^ Lewis, H. G. (1974). "Comments on Selectivity Bias in Wage Comparisons". Journal of Political Economy. 82 (6): 1145–1155. doi:10.1086/260268. S2CID 154754879.
  17. ^ a b Heckman, J. J.; Vytlacil, E. (2007a). "Econometric Evaluation of Social Programs, Part I: Causal Models, Structural Models and Econometric Policy Evaluation". Handbook of Econometrics. 6B. Amsterdam: Elsevier: 4779–4874. doi:10.1016/S1573-4412(07)06070-9.
  18. ^ Lee, L. F. (1978). "Unionism and Wage Rates: A Simultaneous Equation Model with Qualitative and Limited Dependent Variables". International Economic Review. 19 (2): 415–433. doi:10.2307/2526310. JSTOR 2526310.
  19. ^ Willis, R.; Rosen, S. (1979). "Education and Self-Selection". Journal of Political Economy. 87 (5): S7–S36. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.160.3842. doi:10.1086/260821.
  20. ^ Robinson, C.; Tomes, N. (1982). "Self Selection and Interprovincial Migration in Canada". Journal of Economics. 15 (3): 474–502. doi:10.2307/134762. JSTOR 134762.
  21. ^ McElroy, M.; Horney, M. (1981). "Nash Bargained Household Decisions: Toward a Generalization of the Theory of Demand". International Economic Review. 22 (2): 333–349. doi:10.2307/2526280. JSTOR 2526280.
  22. ^ Miller, R. (1984). "Job Matching and Occupational Choice". Journal of Political Economy. 92 (6): 1086–1120. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.560.905. doi:10.1086/261276. S2CID 154097300.
  23. ^ Lazear, E. (1986). "Salaries and Piece Rates". Journal of Business. 106 (1): 405–431. doi:10.1086/296345.
  24. ^ Solon, G. (1988). "Self-Selection Bias in Longitudinal Estimation of Wage Gaps". Economics Letters. 28 (3): 285–290. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(88)90133-4. hdl:2027.42/27523.
  25. ^ Gibbons, R.; Katz, L. (1992). "Does Unmeasured Ability Explain Inter-Industry Wage Differentials?" (PDF). Review of Economic Studies. 59 (3): 515–535. doi:10.2307/2297862. JSTOR 2297862. S2CID 55469856.
  26. ^ Borjas, G. (1990). Friends or Strangers: The Impact of Immigrants on the US Economy. New York, NY: Basic Books. ISBN 9780465025671.
  27. ^ Magnac, T. (1991). "Segmented or Competitive Labor Markets?". Econometrica. 59 (1): 165–187. doi:10.2307/2938245. JSTOR 2938245.
  28. ^ Flinn, C.; Heckman, J. J. (1982). "New Methods for Analyzing Structural Models of Labor Force Dynamics" (PDF). Journal of Econometrics. 18 (1): 115–168. doi:10.1016/0304-4076(82)90097-5. S2CID 16100294.
  29. ^ French, E.; Taber, C. (2011). Ashenfelter, O.; Card, D. (eds.). "Identification of models of the labor market". Handbook of Labour Econometrics. Handbook of Labor Economics. 4A. Amsterdam: Elsevier: 537–618. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.725.5094. doi:10.1016/S0169-7218(11)00412-6. ISBN 9780444534507.
  30. ^ Heckman, J. J.; Ichimura, H.; Smith, J.; Todd, P. (1996). "Sources of selection bias in evaluating social programs: An interpretation of conventional measures and evidence on the effectiveness of matching as a program evaluation method". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 93 (23): 13416–13420. Bibcode:1996PNAS...9313416H. doi:10.1073/pnas.93.23.13416. PMC 24108. PMID 8917606.
  31. ^ Heckman, J. J.; Ichimura, H.; Todd, P. (1997). "Matching as an Econometric Evaluation Estimator: Evidence from Evaluating a Job Training Programme". Review of Economic Studies. 64 (4): 605–654. doi:10.2307/2971733. JSTOR 2971733.
  32. ^ a b Aabring, J.; Heckman, J. J. (2007). "Econometric Evaluation of Social Programs, Part III: Distributional Treatment Effects, Dynamic Treatment Effects, Dynamic Discrete Choice, and General Equilibrium Policy Evaluation". Handbook of Econometrics. 6B. Amsterdam: Elsevier: 5145–5303. doi:10.1016/S1573-4412(07)06072-2.
  33. ^ Heckman, J. J.; Vytlacil, E. (2007b). "Econometric Evaluation of Social Programs, Part II: Using the Marginal Treatment Effect to Organize Alternative Economic Estimators to Evaluate Social Programs and to Forecast Their Effects in New Environments". Handbook of Econometrics. 6B. Amsterdam: Elsevier: 4875–5143. doi:10.1016/S1573-4412(07)06071-0.
  34. ^ Heckman, J. J.; Lochner, L.; Taber, C. (1998). "General-Equilibrium Treatment Effects: A Study of Tuition Policy". American Economic Review. 88 (2): 381–386.
  35. ^ a b Markowitz, H. M. (1952). "Portfolio Selection". Journal of Finance. 7 (1): 77–91. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.x. S2CID 7492997.
  36. ^ Markowitz, H. M. (1991). "Foundations of Portfolio Theory". Journal of Finance. 46 (2): 469–477. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb02669.x.
  37. ^ Markowitz, H. M. (1999). "The Early History of Portfolio Theory". Financial Analysts Journal. 55 (4): 5–16. doi:10.2469/faj.v55.n4.2281.
  38. ^ Bernstein, P. (1992). Capital Ideas. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.
Kembali kehalaman sebelumnya